A buddhist economic system--in principle: Non-attachment to worldly things is doninant but the way of the law is held profitable

by Pryor, Frederic L.

American Journal of Economics & Sociology

Vol. 49 No. 3 Jul.1990

Pp.339-351

Copyright by American Journal of Economics & Sociology


ABSTRACT. Some of the major canonical scriptures of Buddhism are examined, as well as some of the secondary literature about these writings, in order to see what type of economic system might be inferred from the religious tenets which Gautama Buddha expounded. The personal and social ethics underlying such a system, the economic institutions which are consistent with such moral rules and the attitudes toward property and wealth which they inspire are analyzed for the light they shed on the explanation of economic behavior. I Introduction THE NOTION OF BUDDHIST ECONOMICS may seem a contradiction in terms. The Buddhist doctrine of non-self would appear to discourage both production and accumulation, and, moreover, to undermine concern for the economic welfare of others. Its doctrine of nibbana (nirvana) appears both to deny the importance of economic activity and to encourage withdrawal from this world. Its doctrine of kamma (karma) appears to erode any critical analysis of the existing economic order. From such considerations respected authorities on religion, such as Max Weber [1958], argue Buddhism takes an "asocial course" so that there is no "nexus" between the Buddhist ideology and the social order which includes the economy. Nevertheless, governments, in the Asian nations where Buddhism is a living force, are faced with problems in making or implementing economic policy, creating economic institutions, and raising the level of economic development. In this context Buddhist intellectuals have been re-examining their religion to obtain theological perspectives on such policy problems. Further, in the West, scholars of Buddhism are turning, from their focus on Buddhist salvation and contemplation, toward an examination of individual and social ethics of Buddhism (e.g., Sizemore and Swearer [1988]) Finally, certain Western intellectuals are also using Buddhist ideas to describe their view of desirable economic policy.(n1) The topic of Buddhist economics, therefore, seems deserving of consideration. The purpose is to determine whether the most important parts of the Buddhist canon contain a set of doctrines which allow us to gain some coherent ideas about how a modern economic system based upon it should function. Certainly, one finds no systematic exposition about economics in these scriptural sources (or, for that matter, in more modem commentaries(n2)); however, despite their discursiveness and vagueness, enough is available to see a coherent framework. Such an attempt, involves a certain subjectivity, especially since I view these matters through the lenses of a Western trained economist and can only take into account readily available (and translated) primary and secondary source materials, which represent only a fraction of the canon. This discussion of ideas in the formal Buddhist canonical sources does not tell us anything very specific about how Buddhism is actually practiced today, i. e., we cannot easily infer from doctrine to behavior, especially without specification of the social matrix and those particular aspects which a particular group has chosen to adopt or to ignore. To draw a parallel with Christianity, at face value, there is little in the formal doctrines of Calvinism or, for that matter, of the Old Believers of the Russian Orthodox Church which would directly lead someone to suspect that the groups practicing these religions were extremely active in the rise in capitalism that occurred in Western Europe or Russia in the 17th through 19th centuries. To limit further the scope of discussion, I focus primary attention on Theravada rather than Mahayana Buddhism. The former is found in Burma, Cambodia, Laos, Sri Lanka, and Thailand; the latter, in China, India, Japan, Korea, and Vietnam. I also deal only with the formal sources, rather than the legends and myths; the latter may have more direct influence, however, on the actual behavior of practicing Buddhists. II Traditional Buddhist Economic Beliefs as Reflected in the Canon BUDDHISM stems from the teachings of Siddhartha Gautama (ca. 566-ca. 483 B.C.E.) sometimes called Gautama Buddha or the Buddha Sakyamuni (the Enlightened sage of the Sakya clan, to which he belonged). Born in what is now southern Nepal, his teachings--called dhamma (a word also meaning truth, law, norm)-focused on penetrating the obvious, visible aspects of life to determine their essential and true aspects. The ultimate aim of the teachings of the Buddha is the attainment of nibbana (understanding of this reality; dispassion; bliss), transcending the rounds of existence or the cycle of rebirth, and leading a life based on such understanding. A noble but less lofty aim is expressed in the doctrine of kamma (moral justice): to live a life such that sufficient merit has been accumulated to be reborn in a better situation to attain nibbana in a later life. The ethical teachings of the Buddha can only be understood in the light of some of his views about the nature of the world, of which three are of particular relevance for this discussion: First, all mental and physical phenomena are impermanent and life is a process subject to constant change. Thus, our state of material wealth may not last and we must not develop undue attachment to our possessions. Second, the nature of causation regulating the movement of this flux is very broad Our actions and attitudes today, as well as our treatment of nature, have a variety of future consequences not only in this life but our succeeding lives as well (this is part of the doctrine of rebirth). Such an approach provides the basis for a "deep ecology." It also means that moral action (which includes both activity and thoughts) on the part of a group can influence the happiness and prosperity of both the group members and the members of the larger community (through a type of moral radiation discussed below), both in the near and the far future. Third, in its most essential sense, the self does not exist; and that which we call "self" is the result of a misunderstanding about our separation from nature. Thus self-centered ambition is at best only temporarily satisfying; and we must learn to transcend such base passions as selfishness and greed. Personal ethics are an important part of the Buddhist doctrine. In his first sermon,(n3) the Buddha pronounced the Four Noble Truths dealing primarily with the nature of suffering on this earth and its transcendence. The fourth truth is that cessation of such suffering requires a person to follow the Noble Eightfold Path, which consists of a set of prescriptions for attitudes and behavior (discussed below) in our world. Theory and practice (i.e., behavior in this world) are interrelated; suffering is rooted in sensory craving and attachment; and that attachment is fundamentally a state of bondage to the wheel of rebirth operating according to the inevitable law of cause and effect which bring about a moral justice (kamma). That is, suffering is conditioned by both the mind and behavior and through right understanding and activity, a new relationship to the world can be fashioned both now and in our future lives. From such a philosophic base two strands of Buddhism can, for heuristic purposes, be distinguished. A nibbanic strand focuses on soteriological concerns (i.e., salvation or enlightenment), particularly of monks and others who have withdrawn from worldly pursuits. Enlightenment can be most expeditiously gained by shorter or longer withdrawals from the mundane world of family and normal work activities for devotion to spiritual reflection and practice. In contrast to Christian monks, Theravada monks do not participate in normal work and obtain their necessary food by gifts from the laity, in return for teaching them the dhamma. Thus the monk is very much part of this world, albeit occupying a special niche; and moreover, in most places a person can join or resign from the Theravadin monkhood at any time. This emphasis on meditation and withdrawal for the achievement of individual salvation, interpreted in the light of the doctrines of impermanence and non-self, has led to the common belief that Buddhism is a "world denying" and a highly "individualistic" religion. A kammic strand of Buddhism is of greater relevance to the lay person. In his first sermon, the Buddha declared that those wishing to lead a pure life should avoid both the extreme of self-indulgence and asceticism, but rather a person should select a Middle Way. It is important to stress that such a Middle Way does not exclude a comfortable life style or, for that matter, the prosperity associated with economic development. In this important respect Buddhism is not "anti-materialistic. " The moral content of the Middle Way is exemplified by the Noble Eightfold Path right understanding, right thought, right speech, right action, right livelihood, right effort, right mindfulness, and right concentration. Right speech, action and livelihood constitute the sila (moral discipline); of particular importance to economic activity are right action and right livelihood. According to the interpretation by Saddhatissa (1971, pp. 710, right action consists of observing the Five Precepts which include: not to kill but to practice love and harmlessness to all; not to take that which is not given (e.g, theft or deceit) but to practice charity and generosity; not to indulge in false speech but to practice sincerity and honesty; not to partake of intoxicating drinks or drugs which cause heedlessness, but to practice restraint and mindfulness; and not to commit sexual misconduct, but to practice purity and self control. For special occasions or for more dedicated Buddhists five additional precepts are added: to abstain from taking untimely meals; to abstain from worldly amusements; to abstain from use of personal adornments; to avoid sleeping on luxurious beds; and to avoid the handling or possession of gold or silver (which can only really be carried out in the long term by a monk). Popular commentators on right action (e.g., Bodhi, 1984), draw from the "Sigalovada Suttanta" [Suttanta No. 31 in Digha Nikaya] to interpret mindfulness to include working diligently and faithfully fulfilling one's duties to superiors, as well as treating subordinates in a proper manner. Right livelihood or vocation means that the layman should only pursue an occupation that does not cause harm or injustice to other beings. This means laymen are forbidden to deal in arms, in living beings (e.g., slaves or prostitution), in meat, in intoxicating drinks or drugs, and in poisons. Some commentators, drawing upon the canon, also include the taking of usury although this raises some problems.(n4) Longer exegetic exercises of right livelihood (e.g., Sayadaw, 1977) include Four Restraints: from livelihood based on wrong conduct (including the dealing of the five commodities mentioned above); on improper means (this applies primarily to monks); on deception of others; and on low, worldly knowledge (astrology, palmistry, and forecasting). Robin Lovin (1988) makes an interesting point "There is no Buddhist social ethics if one means a single normative form of society that all Buddhists (or even all Theravadins) recognize as applicable in all ages." Thus emphasis is placed on general precepts of behavior applied to specific situations and on the importance of motives underlying behavior (i. e., with correct awareness of the true nature of things). Others stress that the real importance of following the precepts is character building. Although the lay path leads only to a higher rebirth, while the path of a monk can lead to release, it is important to stress that the line between monk and laity is thin because of the fluidity between monk and lay positions. Although the fulfillment of worldly duties was never preached as a way of salvation, a layman can achieve nibbana (with difficulty) or (more easily) by a career change. According to one specialist in Buddhist ethics (Saddhatissa; 1979, p. 120) "it is obvious that a householder after becoming an arahant [a stage in spiritual development], does not remain attached to his home or family." The literature about Buddhism features considerable debate about whether the nibbanic and kammic strands represent "two Buddhisms." Resolving this question is not important for this essay, although it must be noted that both fit within the same philosophic framework and, as I analyze below in greater detail, there is an economic complementarily between the two groups. Some commentators (e.g., Reynolds, 1979) on Buddhist ethics add another cross-cutting distinction between "this-worldly" and "other-worldly" actions so that "four Buddhisms" can be distinguished. In this essay I focus on "this-worldly" actions of the laity. III Teachings on Property, Wealth, and Income A WELL KNOWN BUDDHIST ANALYSIS of the origins of private property is contained in the "Aganna Sutta" [Suttanta No. 27 in Digha Nikaya] sometimes called the "Buddhist Book of Genesis." According to this text, in the beginning there was general prosperity and property in common. Rice was so abundant that when gathered in the evening for supper, a new crop was ready to be gathered for breakfast in the morning. However, certain inequalities--based on physical characteristics--arose and such differentiation led to transgressions from the path of the dhamma, as the more handsome people scorned those with less fortunate endowments. Somewhat later, further transgressions occurred as people maximized utility by collecting and storing rice for several meals, thereby saving some work for themselves and acting in a self-interested manner. A consequence of this latter transgression was a decline in the fecundity of rice, which seems to indicate diminishing returns to the land. Following these events, the Sutta says that the fields were divided and assigned to specific individuals as private property, which in turn gave rise to the stealing of land, lying and other undesirable activities. Three aspects of this story of differentiation leading to "attachment" appear particularly important for our purposes. First, private property in land arose as a pragmatic response to human frailities and economic scarcities which were induced by transgressions from the moral law. Second, private property is by no means a perfect institution and it can give rise to undesirable activities. Nevertheless, I have been unable to find any suggestion in the canon that alternative property arrangements, e.g, a system of community or public ownership, would be better, given the condition of human kind which we find on earth. Third, a later part of the story derives the origins of the caste system from such events. From this story of the origins of property, it should come as no surprise that Buddhist teachings on the nature of wealth reveal some fundamental ambivalences. Fortunately, a recent scholarly conference on this topic (Sizemore and Swearer, 1988) has provided a useful exegesis of these doctrines. Property per se for the layman is not despised. For instance, in the Anguttara-Nikaya, IV, vii, 61) we read of the Fourfold Deserved Bliss of a Layman: the bliss of ownership, the bliss of enjoyment, the bliss of debtlessness, and the bliss of blamelessness. Later in the same source (V, iv, 40) we learn of the five reasons why a person should desire to be rich (by riches obtained by moral means). By his diligence he could make himself happy as well as his family and work people; he could also make happy his friends and companions; he would be able to keep his property from the depredations of weather, robbers, and enemies; he could make suitable offerings to kin, guests, the deceased, and kings; and finally he could offer to recluses and monks. Further, practical advice is given so that one's property is maintained. For instance, in the "Sigalovada Suttanta" (op. cit.), the Buddha cites six ways condicive to loss of property and wealth which should be avoided, of which one is idleness. The property owner is also advised to divide his wealth into four parts one part for living and doing one's duties for others; one part for times of need; and two parts to business (presumably buying intermediate products). If these four parts are of equal size and if the passage refers to the division of income (this is ambiguous), it implies a high amount of savings. Despite these positive views toward wealth, two basic moral ideas must be stressed. First, the owner of such wealth should not be unduly attached to it, nor must he accumulate it by immoral means. To cultivate this non-attachment, a person must be generous and give large parts of it away, specially to the monks. Moreover, the more that is accumulated and then given away, the more a person can cultivate non-attachment (a matter discussed by Kemper, 1988; Reynolds, 1988; and others in Sizemore and Swearer, 1988). Thus wealth is a means for gaining merit. Second, such generosity leads to the accumulation of merit which, in turn, means that a person is reborn to a higher position of wealth and social status; thus inherited wealth is a sign of virtue in a previous life, i. e. accumulated merit. However, such amassing of wealth can also lead to rebirth in a lower social and economic status--even perhaps in hell--if it is carried out by improper means or unskillful mental habits if it is not generously shared; or if it gives rise to pride or greed or other types of improper behavior. In sum, there is a high risk but also a high spiritual and economic return in amassing wealth. The optimal path for accumulating and then giving away wealth does not seem to be specified in the canon; clearly, however, a person's discount rate for wealth in future rebirths cannot be an important factor in arriving at a solution, for a person approaching the problem in this manner would reveal too much attachment to wealth. In possessing wealth, one must not be possessed by wealth.(n5) To complete this discussion it should be emphasized that the Buddha saw no virtue in poverty; indeed, that poverty can be an impediment to virtue. In an oft-cited passage from the Dhammapada Commentary[1969], Book 15, Story 5, pp. 74-76) the Buddha notes that if he is preaching the dhamma while a nearby poor man is suffering from pangs of hunger, he will not be able to be comprehended. However, as soon as the poor man's physical suffering becomes relieved, his mind becomes tranquil and he is open to reason. The same source notes that the ideal city, as described by Buddha, is one where prosperity reigns. Further, poverty raises improper desires--greed and craving--and does not permit a person to be generous. Indeed, in one dialogue, "Cakkavatti-Sihanada Suttanta," [Suttanta No. 26, Digha Nikaya], the Buddha notes that poverty leads to stealing, violence, and murder which is hardly conducive to the conditions leading to the spiritual enrichment of the society or the individual. ording to Swearer and Sizemore (1988), "[f]or the individual, following the d/gamma is not only morally the best and religiously the highest life; it is prudentially the wisest, and ultimately the most profitable. And yet, non-attachment is still the dominant motif: if self-serving greed becomes the motive for such a life, the virtue of even the best action will be lost. Craving destroys the merit of any action and so conformity to the dhammic code for the sake of gain is self-defeating." It should be added that the spiritually most developed look upon all worldly success, even in a future world, as a snare and delusion; and they attempt to transcend this cycle of rebirths by achieving nibbana; but such spiritual virtuosity is only for a self-elected few who, moreover, are capable (in terms of accumulated merit) of carrying out such a task. Notes (n1.) This essay in one of a series ([1985a], [1985b], [1988]) analyzing the ideal economic system of major world religions. Since I focus primarily on Theravada Buddhism, I follow the usual practice in this literature and use the transliterations from the Pali terminology for all religious technical terms, rather than from the Sanskrit; hence nibbana instead of nirvana, kamma instead of karma; dhamma for dharma, etc. For clarity, the Sanskrit terms are placed in parentheses when the terms are first introduced. For the canonical sources I have cited the original numberings; therefore the uppercase Roman numerals generally do not refer to the volume number of the English translation. Two important examples of Western uses of Buddhist ideas are Schumacher [1973] and Kolm 1982]. Unfortunately, neither author focuses on issues of the economic system: Kolm deals with more general economic problems and Schumacher expounds his notion of an ideal economy with only very general references to Buddhist beliefs. (n2.) In the Buddhist literature on economic problems considerable references are made to two discourses of the Buddha (the "Mangala Sutta" and the "Sigalovada Sutta"); however, both are rather vague and discursive. Many references are also made to the practices of the "righteous rulers" who are revered by the Buddhists; and several relevant parts of this literature also receive attention below. For the most part, however, Buddhist economics must be inferred from a close reading of the vast shelf of canonical scriptures but since many of these have not been translated I have relied more on secondary sources than I would have preferred. The only writings of a Buddhist on the specific topic of Buddhist economics which I could locate (de Silva, 1975) turned out to be a slim pamphlet consisting primarily of a favorable commentary on E. F. Schumacher's "Buddhist Economics," which appears to be becoming a favorite text among other Buddhist writers as well. Some important aspects of Buddhist economics can also be found in Buddhist tracts on ethics and politics. (n3.) This sermon is variously called "Setting in Motion the Wheel of Truth" or "The Foundation of the Kingdom of the Norm," and is found in Sanyutta-Nikaya, LVI, Chapter 11. (n4.) Buddhist beliefs about the interest rate are hard to pin down. A number of commentators on Right Livelihood mention that usury is forbidden, but seldom is any canonical text cited except Bodhi (1984), p. 65, who mentions Sutta 117 of the Majjhima-Nikaya. At one point in this sermon to monks the Buddha forbids "rapacity for gain upon gain" which apparently has been translated by others as "usury." However, many of the Buddha's earliest followers were bankers or traders, which suggests that the taking of interest was not forbidden. Further, Kosambi (1%5, pp. 178, 182) notes that several hundred years after the death of the Buddha, Buddhist monasteries often lent part of their monetary wealth to merchants and caravaneers to provide needed capital; presumably such loans yielded considerable interest payments. In reading through the indices of some of the most important books in the canon I have found no other instances where the subject of usury is discussed, and it appears to be a practice which is acceptable in certain circumstances, so long as it is carried out in a proper manner (which I have not found specified); with the right motives; and, I would interpolate, within some minimal deviation from the going market rate. (n5.) The ideal Buddhist lay person is described concisely in a short poem found in the Anguttara-Nikaya (VIII, VI, 54) [5]: From rising and taking action, arranging his matters with care, He who is vigilant orders his living, guards and protects his wares, With confident understanding, moral and willing to bear, Free from the taint of the niggard, he clears a continuous road, Leading to things that are excellent, things of the world beyond. By one who is named the "Truth" there are declared eight things To bring the understanding layman present joy And joy in future worlds. For increased merit Let him be generous, happy to make a gift. I use the translation found in Saddhatissa; 1970], p. 148, rather than the more awkward rendering by Hare (Anguttara-Nikaya, Vol. IV). Bibliography Anguttara-Nikaya, Volumes 111 and IV, trans. by E. M. Hare. The Book of Gradual Sayings for Pali Text Society. London: Luzac, 1961,1%5. -----, Volumes I and 11, trans. by F. L. Woodward, The Book of Gradual Sayings for Pali Text Society. London: Luzac, 1962,1970. Ayal, Eliezer. "Value Systems and Economic Development in Japan and Thailand," Journal of Social Issues, 19, No. 1 (Jan. 1%3), pp. 35-51. Bodhi, Bhikkhu. "The Noble Eightfold Path," The Wheel, No. 308-11. Kandi, Sri Lanka: Buddhist Publication Society, 1984. Buddhadasa, Bhikkhu. Dhammic Socialism, translated and edited by Donald K. Swearer. Bangkok: Thai Inter-Religious Commission for Development, 1986. Dhammapada Commentary, transl. by Eugene Watson Burlingame, ea., Buddhist Legends, Harvard Oriental Series 30, Pali Text Society. London: Luzac, 1969. Digha-Nikaya, trans. by T. W. Rhys Davids. Dialogues of the Buddha, Part 1, Pali Text Society. London: Luzac, 1965. -----, trans. by T. W. Rhys Davids and C. A F. Rhys Davids. Dialogues of the Buddha, Part 111, 5th edition, Pali Text Society. London: Luzac, 1965. Das, Amritandanda. Foundations of Gandhian Economics. New York: St. Martin's, 1979. Gard, Richard A. Buddhism New York: George Braziller, 1962. Jones, Ken. "Buddhism and Social Action," The Wheel, No. 285/6 Kandy, Sri Lanka: Buddhist Publication Society, 1981. Keyes, Charles F. "Buddhist Practical Morality in a Changing Agrarian World: A Case from Northeastern Thailand," in Sizemore and Swearer [1988]. King, Winston L. lIn the Hope of Nibbana. LaSalle, Illinois: Open Court, 1964. Kolm, Serge-Christophe. Economie et bonheur: Bouddhisme profond et modernite Paris: Presses universitaires de France, 1982. Kosambi, D. D. The Culture and Civilization of Ancient India in Historical Outline. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1965. Little, David. "Ethical Analysis and Wealth in Theravaa Buddhism: A Response to Frank Reynolds," in Sizemore and Swearer 119X8]. Lovin, Robin W. "Ethics, Wealth, and Eschatology: Buddhist and Christian Strategies for Change," in Sizemore and Swearer [1988]. Majjhima-Nikaya, Volumes 1,11, and 111, translated by 1. B. Homer for Pali Text Society. The Collection of Middle Length Sayings. London: Luzac, 1957, 1967. Macy, Joanna. Dharma and Development: Religion as Resource in the Sarvodaya Self-Help Movement. West Hartford, Connecticut: Kumarian Press, 1983. Misra, G. S. P. Development of Buddhist Ethics. New Delhi Munshiram Manoharlal Publ., 1984. Nikam, N. A. and McKeon, Richard, eds. The Edicts of Asoka Chicago University of Chicago Press, 1966. Pryor, Frederic L. "The Islamic Economic System A Renew Article," Journal of Comparative Economics, 9, No. 2 (June, 1985a), pp. 197-224. -----, "Some Economics of Utopia: Full Communism," Survey: A Journal of East and West Studies, 29, No. 2 (Summer, 1985b), pp. 70-102. -----, "A Roman Catholic Approach toward an Ideal Economic System," forthcoming 1988. Rajavaramuni, Phra. "Foundations of Buddhist Social Ethics," in Sizemore and Swearer [1988]. Reynolds, Frank E. "Ethics and Wealth in Theavada Buddhism: A Study in Comparative Religious Ethics," in Sizemore and Swearer [1988]. -----, "Four Modes of Theravada Action," Journal of Religious Ethics, 7, No. 1 (Spring 1979), pp. 12-26. Reynolds, Frank E. and Clifford, Regina T. "Sangha, Society, and the Struggle for National Identity: Burma and Thailand," in Frank Reynolds and Ludwig, Theodore, eds. Transition and Transformations in the History of Religions. Leiden: Brill, 1980, pp. 56-91. Reynolds, Frank E. and Reynolds, Mani. Three Worlds According to King Ruang: A Thai Buddhist Cosmology, University of California Research Series 4. Berkeley: Asian Humanities Press, 1982. Saddhatissa, H. Buddhist Ethics: Essence of Buddhism. London: George Allen and Unwin, 1979. Sanyutta-nikaya, translated by F. L. Woodward. The Book of Kindred Sayings V, Pali Text Society, Translation Series No. 16. London: Luzac, 1965. Sarkisyanz, E. "Buddhist Backgrounds of the Burmese Socialism," in Bardwell L. Smith, ed. Religion and the Legitimization of Power in Thailand, Laos, and Burma. Chamberburg, Pa.: ANIMA Books, 1978. Sarkisyanz, E. Buddhist Backgrounds of the Burmese Revolution. The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff, 1965. Sayadaw, Ledi. "The Noble Eightfold Path and Its Factors Explained," The Wheel, No. 245-7. Kandy, Sri Lanka: Buddhist Publication Society, 1977. Schumacher, E. F. "Buddhist Economics," in his Small is Beautiful Economics as if People Mattered. New York: Harper and Row, 1973, pp. 53-63. de Silva, Padmasiri. "The Search for Buddhist Economics," Bodhi Leaves, No. B 69. Kandy, Sri Lanka: Buddhist Publication Society, 1975. Sivaraksa, Sulak. A Buddhist Vision for Renewing Society. Bangkok: Tienwan Publishing House, 1986. Sizemore, Russell F. "Comparative Religious Ethics as a Field: Faith, Culture, and Reason in Ethics," in Sizemore and Swearer [1988]. Sizemore, Russell F. and Swearer, Donald K, eds. Ethics, Wealth and Salvation: A Study Study Buddhist Social Ethics. Forthcoming, 1988. Spiro, Melford E. Buddhism and Society. New York Harper & Row, 1970. Strong, John S. "Rich Man, Poor Man, Bhikkbu, King Asoka's Quinquennial Festival and the Nature of Dana," in Sizemore and Swearer [1988]. Swearer, Donald K. and Sizemore, Russell F. "Preface and Introductory Essay," in Sizemore and Swearer [1988|. Tambiah, Stanley Jeyaraja. The Buddhist Saints of the Forest and the Cult of Amulets A Study in Charisma, Hagiography, Sectarianism, and Millennial Buddhism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984. Weber, Max. Economy and Society, edited by Guenther Roth and Claus Wittich, Volume 11. New York Bedminster Press, 1%8. Weber, Max. The Religion of India: The Sociology of Hinduism and Buddhism, transl. by Hans H. Gerth and Don Martindale. Glencoe: Free Press, 1958. Demography is Basic THE TITLE ALONE, Demography as an Interdiscipline (New Brunswick Transaction Publishers, 1989, paper $17.95) has appeal for the contributors and readers of this Journal. In his Introduction to this collection of papers,J. Mayone Stycos of Cornell University, notes As a field with its own body of interrelated concepts, techniques, journals, and professional associations, demography is clearly a discipline. But by the nature of the subject matter and methods demography is just as clearly an "interdiscipline," drawing heavily on biology and sociology for the study of fertility; on economics and geography for studies of migration, and on the health sciences for analyses of mortality. In economics, ever since Malthus, there has been some concern with population but data and understanding get out of date. Furthermore, the press of an ever more technical and less cultural economics eliminates concern with demographic information and understanding in economics curricula. But there is a very practical need for knowledge and understanding which Stycos's comment above indicates. Indeed, the point can be extended to note simultaneity in the relationship of demographics to peripheral subjects. I recall the comment of a friend and former advisor to the government of an African (largely Moslem) nation who said the ruler was willing to listen to their advice on all matters except population control. His comment to them, as memory serves, was, "No! No! My people like to have many children." It is the recognition of such sentiments that keeps a ruler ruling! A case where bad advice was given and, unfortunately, taken was provided by the food price riots in Egypt which had followed some advice from international agencies. Advice given without a depth of understanding of history, culture and the social and political milieu may be incompetent advice. The stated summary of the first paper by Samuel H. Preston should whet some appetites. Four essentially independent conceptions of the population problem are visible in current discussions. One is derived from macroeconomics, one from microeconomics, one from the health sciences, and one from ethical concerns about the just relation between man and nature After describing these conceptions, this paper addresses the population problem principally using the economic definitions. It cites five reasons why discussions of the economic hazards posed by population growth have become markedly less alarmist in the past decade. Failures of highly quantified input-output models to account for human progress are emphasized. The paper presents examples of how technical demography had shed light on the dimensions of and solutions to the population problem and concludes with a brief discussion of contemporary population problems in the U.S. Preston includes a quotation from Kenneth Boulding, who could never be accused of ignoring the relevant areas of human concern peripheral to economics. It bears reproduction here. The real world consists not of numbers but of shapes and sizes. It is topological rather than quantitative. Quantification for the most part is a prosthetic device of the human mind, though certainly a very useful one. Anyone who thinks that numbers constitute the real world, however, is under an illusion, and this is an illusion that is by no means uncommon. ("Science: Our Common Heritage." Science 207:831-836 at 833). Needless to say many confusions and out-of-date conceptions will be removed from the minds of the readers of these eight substantial contributions to knowledge and understanding. (Passages quoted with permission of the publisher). FRANK C. GENOVESE Clientelist Politics in Colombia COLOMBIA is an old democracy with a constitution. It has also a well earned reputation as one of the most violent nations in the world. Its drug trafficking and the crimes that go with it are reported daily. This paradox is discussed by Jorge Pablo Osterling in Democracy in Colombia: Clientelist Politics & Guerrilla Warfare, (New Brunswick, NJ.: Transaction Books, 1989). The history of clientelismo (a system of boss-client relationship that manipulates elections and public sector jobs) which is rampant in Colombia explains one of the difficulties in eradicating the drug traffickers who wield economic power and political influence. C.E.G. ~~~~~~~~ By FREDERIC L. PRYOR(*) (*) [Frederic L. Pryor, Ph.D., is professor of economics at Swarthmore College, Swarthmore, PA 19801.] This paper is one of a series reporting the author's research on the influence of religion on economic and social behavior. The article uses the Pali transliteration rather than the Sanskrit; it is Theravada Buddhism, not the Mahayana, which is discussed in it. Gratitude for useful comments is due to Steven 1. Piker, Robert Pryor, Zora Pryor, Donald A. Swearer, and Larry Westphal.