The Winds of Change: Buddhism and the Maritime Links of Early South Asia, by Ray, Himanshu P.
Reviewed by Roderich Ptak
The Journal of the American Oriental Society Vol.116 No.3 July-Sep 1996 pp.585-586
COPYRIGHT 1996 American Oriental Society
Himanshu P. Ray has published widely in scholarly journals and is especially well known for her studies on early maritime trade in South Asia and the Indian ocean. The present monograph is a fresh and critical survey of this subject, taking a bird's-eye view. It pulls together archaeological and written evidence from a large number of sources and tries to establish a general picture of South Asia's maritime links in the period from c. 300 or 200 B.C. to c. 400 to 500 A.D. This includes commercial, cultural, and religious contacts. The geographical area covered by Ray's book is the northern half of the Indian Ocean, from the Persian Gulf and the Red Sea at the one end to the Indonesian archipelago and continental southeast Asia at the other end. Both long-distance connections and coastal links are considered. The description of the latter chiefly concerns the Indian coasts. Some remarks on China and the South China Sea are included as well, but East Africa is of no relevance. The book contains an introduction and five major chapters. These focus on the following subjects: the evolution of early trading networks and the organization of maritime trade in the Indian Ocean; South Asia's relations with the Near East and the Mediterranean world; South Asia's links across the Bay of Bengal to continental and insular southeast Asia; the role which Buddhism played in the evolution of trading networks and cultural contacts; the nautical and sailing technology of early Indian Ocean shipping. There is also a brief conclusion, an excellent bibliography, and an index. Ray's book discusses a number of interesting points that previous studies on Asia's maritime links often presented in a different light. Here only some points will be listed. First, according to Ray, the growth of trade along transoceanic and overland routes in the post-Mauryan period came as a result of events taking place in the Ganges valley from about 500 B.C. onwards; this means that external factors were of minor importance. Second, sea trade was not only in expensive luxury items but also in subsistence goods, including agricultural and other products. Third, the role of Graeco-Roman shipping in the Indian Ocean was not as crucial as some scholars have thought; other networks such as the South Asian and Arab networks also contributed to the distribution of trade commodities and cultural elements. Fourth, expansion of trade in the early historical period can be linked to certain shifts and changes in the dominant ideology; the emergence and spread of Buddhism at a time of growing urban centres in India was a key factor in the growth of maritime contacts along the Indian littoral and to Southeast Asia. The last point is of particular concern because it touches the question of Southeast Asia's so-called "Indianization." There are different opinions on how, why, and when Indian influence began to spread and on the mechanics and frequency of early links across the Bay of Bengal. By and large, Ray seems to be in favor of de Casparis' ideas on this subject. This means that the notion of an "initial" Indianization should be replaced by a concept of long-lasting transoceanic relations between the various parts of each of the two regions involved - South and Southeast Asia - and between the two macro-regions themselves. At the Southeast Asian end this does, of course, presuppose a concept of "statehood" somewhat different from the one found in early Chinese descriptions of this region. Clearly, a survey of a complex subject such as Asia's early maritime links cannot take account of all details, nor can it solve all riddles. In fact, in many cases it is impossible to move beyond a level of general assumptions and a set of simple models. Archaeological data may abound but they are rarely helpful in determining the size of commodity flows, profits, incomes, and other quantitative variables crucial to the economic historian. Vague indicators may tell us something about the concurrent existence of early networks and the conditions and circumstances under which they emerged, but the relative importance of these networks and the agents who operated them is usually difficult to assess for lack of quantitative evidence. Similar constraints restrict the analysis of sociological and other data. There can be no doubt that Ray is perfectly aware of this dilemma. Therefore, the mosaic she offers to the reader is a mixture of carefully selected facts and cautiously formulated hypotheses with, in the case of the latter, frequently more than one option. It is this thoughtfulness on the part of the author and the skillful way in which a myriad of facets are woven together, that make the present volume a state-of-the-art study. I may not be very polite, then, to criticize individual points in a comprehensive work such as this one, but some minor things caught my attention, of which two or three should be mentioned. Referring to the accounts of Marco Polo, Zhao Rugua, and other medieval writers in the context of early maritime trade may be useful if one is to comment on certain long-term developments, but if no evidence is available from the early period itself, it is often risky to infer from a later source that a particular situation was characteristic also of the preceding centuries. Some primary sources and their respective English translations were only quoted through secondary works; the reader is left to find the original references himself. Much is said on maritime links, especially on trade, but only one chapter is exclusively reserved for the role of Buddhism; although this chapter is excellently written, it seems to me that this is not enough to justify fully the present title of the book; in fact, when I first read the title, I had expected more on Buddhism and less on trade. Relations between Madagascar and Southeast Asia are only briefly touched upon. The same applies to the problem of the Kunlun traders and other phenomena amply documented in the various translations of Chinese sources that were not systematically used at all. Some commodities and their distribution are not mentioned or do not appear in the index. In all, however, I found this book an interesting and very valuable contribution to a field of study that attracts a growing number a scholars both in Asia and the West. RODERICH PTAK UNIVERSITY OF MUNICH